Logo: Independent Community Bankers of America - ICBA The Nation's Voice for Community Banks (R)
Username:
Password:

Graphic: Arrow Forgot password?
Graphic: Arrow Request Login
Contact ICBA Site Map Search ICBA
ArrowICBA Home





Members Only = Access Restricted
Last update: 08/23/14

FDIC Options Paper on Deposit Insurance: Coverage Limits

WWR ARTICLE
OCTOBER 6, 2000

 

FDIC OPTIONS PAPER ON DEPOSIT INSURANCE: COVERAGE LIMITS

Editor’s note: This is the third in a series of articles that will take a more in-depth look at the three major issues raised in the FDIC’s options paper on deposit insurance reform. The FDIC would welcome banker comments on these issues, as would we.

The third and last major issue addressed by the FDIC options paper on deposit insurance is how to set coverage levels. To date, coverage limits have been set on an ad hoc basis, with Congress revisiting the issue from time to time and establishing a new limit. Since 1934, the basic coverage amount has increased five times, from $5,000 to $100,000. The ad hoc setting of coverage limits results in fluctuations in the real value of deposit insurance, the paper notes. Most of the increases have more or less been consistent with cost-of-living adjustments, except for the 1980 increase to $100,000, which was much higher than needed to keep pace with inflation.

Based on the CPI, the current $100,000 coverage limit has declined in real value by half since 1980. “This raises the question of whether Congress wishes to continue providing the same level of insurance protection for consumers in real terms, or to allow the coverage level to erode in value by maintaining the status quo,” the paper states.

Coverage limits represent a “balance between the goals of deposit insurance [protection of small savers, promotion of financial stability, and maintenance of the viability of small banks], on the one hand, and the need to limit moral hazard and the risk to taxpayers and the insurance funds, on the other,” according to the options paper.

The immediate effect on the BIF and SAIF fund balances and the risk to the funds of an increase in coverage is uncertain and the long-term effect even more so, the FDIC says, and further analysis is needed. One preliminary estimate of the immediate effect of a doubling of the coverage limit is that about $230 billion of uninsured deposits would immediately become insured and reduce the reserve ratios of the combined BIF and SAIF to about 1.28 percent.

The long-term effect depends on whether an increase in coverage would cause a change in consumer and business behavior leading to a larger proportion of new wealth being placed in deposits or existing assets transferred to deposits. The FDIC suggests that in the long run a coverage increase might not change the amount of insured deposits because consumers already have the ability to place all their assets in insured accounts by using multiple account coverage or spreading deposits among different banks. On the other hand, changes in demographics—an aging population with a preference for CD investments, decreased issuance of Treasury securities as the nation enjoys budget surpluses, or increased financial market volatility could result in a shift of household assets into insured deposits.

The paper also discusses whether an increase in coverage would increase insurance losses in the event of bank failures. Some view the 1980 increase to $100,000 as playing a key role in the savings and loan crisis, as brokered deposits provided funding for high risk institutions. The FDIC notes, however, that a confluence of many factors explains the magnitude of the crisis.

Higher coverage levels are not likely to increase systemic risk because of the minimal effect they would have on the magnitude of risk posed by large institutions, the FDIC states. For these institutions it is the implicit guarantee that uninsured deposits or creditors would be protected (too big to fail)—not explicit coverage limits—that will result in high losses. The FDIC suggests that ways other than raising the coverage limit also should be explored to level the playing field between large and small banks. Examples given include “haircutting” uninsured deposits or creditors in the event of a large bank failure, or assessing large banks for more of the costs of too-big-to-fail protections.

The paper also addresses small bank funding issues. As small banks find it more difficult to fund operations with deposits, they will turn to other more expensive and interest-rate sensitive funding sources, such as FHLB advances. But funding with FHLB advances versus insured deposits does not reduce the risk exposure or loss severity to the insurance funds or taxpayers when a bank fails, because FHLB advances are fully secured and stand ahead of the FDIC in liquidation. In addition, when banks fund themselves with deposits, the FDIC at least collects premium income.

Options

The options for setting appropriate coverage limits outlined in the paper include:

  • Status Quo. Congress could continue setting coverage limits on an ad hoc basis as needed.

  • Formal Indexing. Indexing of coverage limits would require selection of an index, the base year, and the adjustment mechanism. Depending on the index and base year chosen, wide variations in the coverage limit result. As mentioned, indexing the $100,000 coverage for inflation since 1980 yields a limit of $198,000; but the $40,000 limit set in 1974 would be $132,000 today, and the $5,000 limit set in 1934 would be only $61,000. Setting coverage to a multiple of per capita income rather than the CPI results in coverage of $130,000 to $280,000 depending on the base year selected. Other possible indexes such as wages or household wealth would yield yet different results.

  • Simplification. The current multiple account rules with separate coverage for accounts held by the same person in separate rights and capacities make the coverage limits higher than $100,000 in practice, the paper notes. Simplifying the coverage rules could alter the effective coverage limit. One option would be to combine simplification of the coverage rules with a higher nominal limit. Simplification could reduce the time and resources that bankers spend training their staff in the intricacies of the rules and explaining them to the public. It would also reduce the erroneous advice given to bank customers when bank personnel misunderstand the rules.

  • Additional Coverage for Municipal Deposits. Proponents of this option argue it would allow small banks to compete more effectively for public deposits and reduce the administrative burdens associated with state collateralization requirements. The FDIC estimates that full coverage of the existing $114 billion of uninsured municipal deposits held by banks and thrifts would reduce the reserve ratio of a combined BIF and SAIF to 1.32 percent. However, full coverage could attract additional municipal deposits into the system, reducing the reserve ratio further. State and local governments hold over $1 trillion in financial assets.

    Some have suggested that full coverage of municipal deposits will not increase the risk exposure to the FDIC because collateralized deposits already stand ahead of the FDIC in a bank failure. But the FDIC notes that the pledging requirement places a limit on the amount of deposits an institution can attract while 100 percent FDIC coverage would not. In addition, full coverage of municipal deposits could increase risk by increasing moral hazard, the FDIC notes, because public units will have no incentive to monitor the risk behavior of the institution.

    The FDIC also notes that small institutions may not be able to compete for municipal deposits if higher coverage levels result in large banks bidding up the interest rates.

    To address these concerns, the FDIC suggests the options of providing higher coverage for “in-market” municipal deposits only and raising the coverage for in-state municipal deposits to some multiple of basic coverage, but not to 100 percent.

  • Optional Excess Coverage. Private “excess” deposit insurance coverage is currently available from a few insurance companies. Coverage is typically limited to $5 to $ million per institution and premiums range from 10 to cents per $100 of coverage. Surveys indicate only a relatively small percentage of banks purchase this excess coverage. In addition to private excess insurance, one option is for the FDIC to offer optional excess coverage. The key issues would be what amount of coverage to offer and how to price it. Presumably there would be a surcharge above the regular premiums paid for basic coverage.

    Another option would be for the FDIC to guarantee private excess insurance. The FDIC would have to have the right to refuse to issue the guarantee if a review of the terms of the insurer’s contracts or its financial condition were unacceptable.

    The last option mentioned in the paper is coinsurance for deposits over $100,00. Although never implemented, the original plan for deposit insurance was to provide full protection for the first $10,000 per depositor, 75 percent of the next $40,000 and 50 percent of all deposits over $50,000.

The options paper is posted on the FDIC Web site (www.fdic.gov), along with a series of questions designed to elicit public comment. Viewers can respond to the questions directly on line. Among the questions posed on coverage limits are: whether the coverage limit should be indexed to prices, income or wealth; whether a higher coverage limit would address funding concerns at smaller institutions and allow them to compete with large institutions for deposits; whether full coverage, or other limit higher than basic coverage, should be provided for municipal deposits; whether the FDIC should provide optional excess coverage; and whether deposit insurance rules regarding multiple account coverage should be simplified.

Note: Previous articles in this series covered the issues of pricing risk at individual banks (Sept. 8 edition of Washington Weekly Report) and funding deposit insurance losses over time (Sept. 29 edition).






ArrowsPrintable version



Button: Share

All contents copyright 2014 Independent Community Bankers of America. All rights reserved.
Privacy Statement | Legal Notice